class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide # Elasticity and tax ## Week 4 ### Krisna Gupta ### 1 March 2021 (updated: 2021-03-01) --- ## Recap on last week - We use consumer and producer surplus to measure the efficiency of the economy. We want the combination of both to be generally bigger. - The two face a constant political battle: consumer wants small prices, producers like high prices. - When market is perfect, intervention often leads to various types of inefficiency --- ## Today - We will learn about one more intervention: tax. - before we go there, it is best to understand elasticity first. --- ## What's an elasticity? - If you are a business owner, understanding elasticity is important aspect to get maximized profit. - **Price elasticity of demand** of a good is a concept of how much the demand of that good change its price changes. - we usually just say **elasticity** in short. - Maximizing profit requires this knowledge: - sometimes it is better to sell cheap to gain huge market share, or sell high if niche. --- ## Calculating elasticity .pull-left[ - Consider the demand curve on the right. - At `\(P_1=10\)`, the daily traffic is `\(Q_1=140\)` - When `\(P_2=11\)`, daily traffic drops to `\(Q_2=127.3\)` ] .pull-right[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik1-1.png)<!-- --> ] --- ## Calculating elasticity .s[ - To calculate elasticity of demand, we first calculate: 1. percent change in the quantity demanded 1. percent change in the price - Formula for no.1: $$ \tag{1} \text{% change in }Q^D=\frac{Q_2^D-Q_1^D}{Q_1^D}\times 100 $$ - Formula for no.2: $$ \tag{2} \text{% change in P}=\frac{P_2-P_1}{P_1}\times 100 $$ ] --- ## Calculating elasticity - for our case, we have: $$ `\begin{align*} Q_1^D&=140 & Q_2^D&=127.3 \\ P_1&=10 & P_2&=11 \end{align*}` $$ - Thus: $$ `\begin{align} \text{% change in }Q^D &= \frac{127.3-140}{127.3}\times 100 \\ &=-10 \% \end{align}` $$ $$ `\begin{align} \text{% change in P} &= \frac{11-10}{10}\times 100 \\ &=10\% \end{align}` $$ --- ## Calculating elasticity - After we get the numbers from {1} and {2}, we use this formula: .s[ $$ \tag{3} \text{Price elasticity of demand}=\frac{\text{% change in }Q^D}{\text{% change in P}} $$ ] - in our case, we have: .s[ $$ `\begin{align} \text{Price elasticity of demand}&=\frac{-10\%}{10\%} \\ &=-1 \end{align}` $$ ] --- ## Calculating elasticity - Economists are also lazy in writing the minus sign. - Usually we report demand elasticity in **absolute term**. - i.e., we drop the minus sign. - However, since most demand curves are downward sloping, it must be negative - hence we automatically knows what it means even when we report in absolute term. --- ## About percent change Using percent changes is more useful than absolute changes - Things are usually move on proportion - A wealthy person will feel casual getting 1 million IDR because it's probably just a small % of her total wealth. - Quantity and prices have many metrics - kgs, litres, units, pairs, units/day, etc - IDR, USD, btc, etc. --- class:middle, center # Note In the exam, please use 3 digits decimals. for example, `\(\pi= 3.14159265359...\)` please report `\(\pi=3.142\)` on exam. --- class: middle, center ## interpreting elasticity <iframe src="https://giphy.com/embed/WYEWpk4lRPDq0" width="400" height="400" frameBorder="0" class="giphy-embed" allowFullScreen></iframe><p><a href="https://giphy.com/gifs/cat-WYEWpk4lRPDq0">via GIPHY</a></p> --- ## Interpreting elasticity - We have seen the elasticity of our toll road case is around 1, but what does this mean? - Note that the elasticity formula has % change in Q at the top, and % change in P at the bottom. - In a sense, the number shows how much quantity change given the price change. - that means, the bigger the number of the price elasticity, **the more elastic it is** --- <iframe src="https://embed.polleverywhere.com/multiple_choice_polls/TZKSFQSoTy9c3aEnRAq2N?controls=none&short_poll=true" width="800px" height="600px"></iframe> --- class: center, middle ## A market is elastic. So what? Let's have a look at different 'kind' of elasticities and what they mean We'll begin with two extreme cases of elasticity: zero (0) and infinity ( `\(\infty\)` ) --- ## Two extreme cases of elasticity - Suppose the toll road is the only way to go to work. - No matter how high the price, people will still need to use it. - Hence, change in the demand of toll road is zero for any change in price. - Suppose shuttlecocks are priced 10.000 IDR - If people don't care about the shuttlecocks' color, everyone will buy the pink one if the price drop to 9.900 IDR - Everyone won't buy a single one if the price go up only to 10.100 IDR --- ## Two extreme cases of elasticity .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik2-1.png)<!-- --> .s[an illustration of **perfectly inelastic demand**] ] .pull-right[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik3-1.png)<!-- --> an illustration of **perfectly elastic demand**] --- ## Types of elasticities - Most goods are somewhere in between. - We usually use elasticity=1 as another important division point. - 1 is a useful barrier because when elasticity=1, that means a change in price by 1 % leads to a change in quantity demanded by 1 % - elasticity < 1 means the quantity response less than a change in prices, while elasticity > 1 means the quantity is highly responsive, more than the change in price. --- .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik4-1.png)<!-- -->![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik4-2.png)<!-- --> ] .pull-right[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik5-1.png)<!-- --> </br> </br> </br> The flatter the curve, the closer its elasticity to `\(\infty\)`] --- ## Types of demand elasticities | Elasticity | meaning | | ---------- | ------- | | 0 | **perfectly inelastic**. Price doesn't matter | | < 1 | **inelastic**. Quantity is less responsive to price changes | | 1 | **unit elastic**. Quantity change exactly the same as the price change in % terms| | >1 | **elastic**. Quantity response heavily to price changes | | `\(\infty\)` | **perfectly elastic**. A slight increase of price reduces demand to zero | --- ## Elasticities vary. So what? - Suppose you wan't to increase the revenue from the toll road operation, what price will you set? - It is intuitive to think that the higher the price, the better. - High price `\(\Rightarrow\)` more revenue - Is there a problem with this logic? -- - Remember, demand respond to price. High price `\(\Rightarrow\)` lower demand `\(\Rightarrow\)` less revenue - The maximum price depends on the demand elasticity --- ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik6-1.png)<!-- --> --- ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik7-1.png)<!-- --> --- ## Impact of price increase .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik8-1.png)<!-- --> ] .pull-right[.s[ - Segment A is the **Quantity effect of price increase** - Negative effect since fewer units sold - Segment C is the **Price effect of price increase** - positive effect since higher price for each unit sold ]] --- ## Impact of price increase .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik9-1.png)<!-- --> ] .pull-right[ - If you are profit oriented, Increasing the price is a good idea if: $$ B+C > B+A $$ $$ C>A $$ ] --- ## Impact of price increase .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik10-1.png)<!-- --> ] .pull-right[ - In a market with high demand elasticity, the quantity effect outweighs the price effect. - Increasing the price is not so clever if the market's demand is highly elastic. ] --- <iframe src="https://embed.polleverywhere.com/multiple_choice_polls/qLnFtZvFnbb5LL6PGKaeB?controls=none&short_poll=true" width="800px" height="600px"></iframe> --- ## Last point on demand elasticity - When elasticity = 1, then `\(A=C\)` - hence changing price has no impact on sales revenue. - Profit oriented in the real life may not very realistic - Governments may want to serve as much people as possible - In the short run, growth and market cap may be more important than profit. --- ## Last point on demand elasticity - We usually tied elasticity on a price point. - on our toll road case, our price point is 10.000 IDR - Elasticity may differ in different price point. - Changing price from 10 to 11 may have different impact compared to changing price from 20 to 21. - the first one is an increase of 10%. - the second one is an increase of 5%. - in absolute term, both are a 1.000 IDR increase. --- ## Last point on demand elasticity - Estimating elasticity is very hard - There are many things also at play: - different condition in different time - different buyer with different characteristics behave differently - Income, taste, etc matters (remember what **shifts the demand curve?**) --- ## Factors determine demand elasticity - A **necessity** good tend to have lower elasticity compared to a **luxury good**. - The availability of **close substitutes**, like the case with pertamax and shell. - **Share of income spent** on the good. Rich people may not care with toll road price. - **Time**. Cigarettes may have low elasticity in the short run because it is so addictive, and adapt later in the long run. --- ## Other types of demand elasticity - **Cross price elasticity of demand** is how the price of good `\(B\)` affects a demand of good `\(A\)`. .s[ $$ \tag{4} \text{Cross-Price elasticity}_{A,B}=\frac{\text{% change in }Q_A}{\text{% change in }P_B} $$ ] - When good A and good B are subtitutes, then the effect is negative. - e.g., Samsung and Xiaomi - When good A and good B are complements, the effect is positive. - e.g., Samsung and Telkomsel --- ## Other types of demand elasticity - **Income elasticity of demand** is how the chanage on income affects your demand of good `\(A\)` .s[ $$ \tag{5} \text{Income elasticity of Demand}_A=\frac{\text{% change in }Q_A}{\text{% change in Income}} $$ ] - It is usually positive if good `\(A\)` is a **normal good**. - It is negative if good `\(A\)` is an **inferior good**. - you buy less instant noodle when you're richer. --- ## Other types of demand elasticity - **Income elasticity of demand** is how the chanage on income affects your demand of good `\(A\)` .s[ $$ \tag{5} \text{Income elasticity of Demand}_A=\frac{\text{% change in }Q_A}{\text{% change in Income}} $$ ] - A **necessity** good is usually **income inelastic** because you need to buy it no matter what. - A **luxury** good can be **income elastic**. You only buy it if your main needs are covered so you can wait for a discount. --- class:middle, center # Price elasticity of Supply --- ## Price elasticity of Supply - Supply also have elasticities. As a supplier, you can't afford to sell expensive if there are high competition. - However, in many cases (such as toll road), entering the market is very hard. - How easy it is to expand (or for new supplier to enter the market) matters to how responsive can supply react to the change in price. .s[ $$ \tag{6} \text{Price elasticity of supply} = \frac{\text{% change in }Q^s}{\text{% change in }P} $$ ] --- ## Two extreme cases of elasticity .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik11-1.png)<!-- --> .s[an illustration of **perfectly inelastic supply**] ] .pull-right[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafik12-1.png)<!-- --> .s[an illustration of **perfectly elastic supply**]] --- ## Two extreme cases of elasticity - In a **perfectly inelastic supply** case, the market can't supply more even if the price increase. Toll road is like this: Building more toll road is expensive and takes time. Most times this is monopolized by the government. - In a **perfectly elastic supply**, the market supply exactly zero when the price go up just by a little. A highly competitive market where all firms operate at the margin may behave this way. - Again, most times, the supply curve is somewhere in between. --- ## What changes supply elasticity? - A market tend to have a highly elastic price elasticity of supply when **inputs are abundant** and can be converted in and out of producion at a very low cost. - Matters, as price elasticity of supply tend to be higher in the long run. Increasing production capacity may takes time since investing in a new land, building or machine requires **time**. - Some goods are even impossible to be increased, hence have zero elasticity. Radio spectrum is one example. --- class: center ## European farm surplus European Union **subsidised** their farmers heavily. They probably knew that subsidies create huge **surplus** (remember last week), but they thought the surplus would not be as big since farming land is **limited**. However, EU farmers were able to expand production using things like fertilizers and pesticides, which are **readily available inputs**. --- class: middle, center # The benefits and costs of taxation --- ## Excise Tax (_cukai_) - The government often tax goods in the form of an excise tax. - In Indonesia, some goods have an excise to its purchase: - Cigarettes & alcohol - Luxury goods (PPnBM) - You can say that a value-added tax is another form of an excise tax. --- ## How tax works - Tax acts like a price ceiling plus plus floor: - The government set a higher price for consumers to pay - At the same time, the producers are forced to produced at a lower price. - A reminder: in a **price floor** scenario, surplus from consumer transferred to the producer, while in a **price ceiling**, surplus transferred from producers to consumers. - in tax case, CS and PS are transferred to the government. --- ## The impact of tax ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafiks3-1.png)<!-- --> --- ## The impact of taxation .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafiks6-1.png)<!-- --> ] .pull-right[.s[ - The market price is `\(P=P_E\)` - The price paid by consumers is `\(P=P_C\)` - Producer receive payment at `\(P=P_P\)` - The tax per purchased good paid to the government is `\(t=P_C-P_P\)` ]] --- ## The impact of taxation .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafiks7-1.png)<!-- --> ] .pull-right[.s[ - Consumer lose `\(A+B\)` - Producer lose `\(C+D\)` - The government collects tax revenue `\(TR=T \times Q_T\)` - This is equals to `\(TR=A+C\)` - `\(B+D=DWL\)` ]] --- ## The impact of taxation - As we learn, the tax revenue and the size of DWL depends highly in demand elasticity and supply elasticity of the good. - The less elastic the demand and supply of a good, the higher revenue gained from taxing the good. - i.e., price effect > quantity effect. - DWL also lower when the demand and/or supply of the good is highly inelastic. --- .pull-left[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafiks1-1.png)<!-- -->![](week4_files/figure-html/grafiks1-2.png)<!-- --> ] .pull-right[ ![](week4_files/figure-html/grafiks2-1.png)<!-- -->![](week4_files/figure-html/grafiks2-2.png)<!-- --> ] --- ## Implication - If the government wants to collect revenue, its best to impose a tax on a good with low elasticities. - If the government wants to change behaviour, tax a good with high elasticities. - Taxing cigarettes to discourage smoking maybe ineffective - however, it can be used to gain revenue. - Highly inelastic goods may suggest it's a necessity: people may be unhappy with the tax. --- ## Implication - Same goes with the business people: be careful in increasing price if your product is highly elastically demanded. - Next week, we will have a look a bit more detailed on the supply curve: - what drives the elasticity of supply. - Different types of cost. --- ## Some recap before da quiz - Elasticities is very important in determining surpluses: CS, PS, revenues. - Elasticities can be estimated (albeit hard). - Elasticities vary: `\(0 \leq 1 \leq \infty\)` . - Many factors influence elasticities. - You should be able to use elasticity formula and can draw how tax is calculated and drawn. --- class: middle, center .s[ ### End of slides ] # Thank You <iframe src="https://giphy.com/embed/NIsWtysJUrvTG" width="480" height="320" frameBorder="0" class="giphy-embed" allowFullScreen></iframe><p><a href="https://giphy.com/gifs/cute-NIsWtysJUrvTG">via GIPHY</a></p>